Please note the content on this website is for Investment Professionals only and should be shared responsibly. No other persons should rely on the information contained within this website.
Logo of Bond Vigilantes
Thursday 17 April 2025

When analysing long-term investments, the primary focus is naturally on the potential total returns. Your final profit is simply a function of the future actual returns of the investment, less the original cost.

In the realm of fixed interest bonds, this calculation is relatively straightforward. For instance, you can estimate the likely return using the redemption yield, as the coupon is set, and the redemption date and value are known. This predictability allows for a clear definition and  a strong approximation of future profits.

However, in equities, this predictability is not attainable. Returns are a function of the dividend payments made by the company and the future performance of the business, both of which are uncertain. At the end of the period, there is no set redemption value; you remain invested, and to convert your investment back into actual cash, a sale has to be made. The final value remains at the vagaries of future market valuations.

So, what should you buy on any given day, bonds or equities? What should your weighting be? There is no definitive answer, particularly if focused on short-term investment horizons; however, some guidelines can help predict likely long-term outcomes. Equity returns, in particular, appear to become more predictable over extended periods, though this appears to be a function of the starting price paid.


Source: M&G, Bloomberg, 31 December 2024. Past performance is not a guide to future performance.

The chart above shows the subsequent 10-year annualised returns on the S&P 500 based on the starting valuation, as measured using the forward P/E ratio. Unsurprisingly, given the total return is a combination of the starting price and investment outcome, we find that the initial valuation is a significant driver of the eventual outcome, similar to the total return aspect of bond yields. As the above chart depicts, historically, higher valuations have been associated with lower subsequent 10-year returns, and at current levels, forward returns have averaged just 1.6%.

Given the question we are trying to answer is whether investors should prefer equities over bonds, it is essential to consider equity valuations in the context of bond valuations. The chart below depicts the relationship between the S&P 500’s forward P/E ratio and 10-year US Treasury yields. Each dot represents a historical data point, showing the historic level of Treasury yields at different historical equity valuation levels, with the current P/E range  shaded in white. 


Source: M&G, Bloomberg, 31 December 2024.

The final step in our analysis is to combine the first two charts seen thus far, overlaying the treasury yields with historical equity returns. This helps define a break-even curve, a threshold where investors would have been indifferent between investing in equities or bonds based on historical returns.


Source: M&G, Bloomberg, 31 December 2024.

This provides us with a historical plot indicating where equities were likely to provide a superior return to bonds and should have therefore  been overweighted, and vice versa. Points to the left of the curve indicate periods when equities were cheaper, as their forward “expected” returns exceeded Treasury yields, and points to the right of the curve represent points where bonds were cheaper, delivering “expected” higher returns than equities. We could name this curve the ‘WOOLY curve’, based on the Weighted Outlook of Long-term Yields. This line indicates where, based on historic norms, one may be indifferent between equities and bonds.

This exercise explores historical starting points to determine potential asset allocation. As of the 1st of January 2025, it would depict that if we invested $10,000 in a bond on the 31st of December 2024 and held it for ten years, assuming it compounds at the redemption yield of 4.6%, the investment would grow to approximately $15,700. In contrast, using the historical data from the first chart, a $10,000 investment in the S&P 500 at year end valuations would have an “expected” return of 1.6% per annum, resulting in a final value of $11,700 over the same 10-year period. Essentially, based on this analysis, bonds are expected to outperform equities by approximately 40% over the next 10 years.

This is investing 101 as outlined by Benjamin Graham in the Intelligent Investor. Bond yields and equity yields are both income streams that are then discounted to create a present value, which gives us the equity risk premium. The two should be compared, and asset allocation decisions should be analysed accordingly. Warren Buffett has constantly noted, future returns are not random, but depend on your starting point.

The above charts do not suggest that 10-year US treasuries are cheap or that the S&P 500 is expensive. However, they do indicate a strong possibility that, from an investor’s perspective at current valuations, one is historically a better bet than the other. Starting yields have historically provided a potential guide to future investment returns and portfolio weightings.

I hope you agree that this is more than just Wooly thinking!

In order to take a dispassionate look at this important discussion, we will focus solely on current long-term market-implied forecasts and work from there. The best way to explore this is to plot the 30-year interest rate swap. This represents the market’s pricing of average short-term interest rates over the next 30 years.

This is the average cash rate. At times, the short-term rate will be above the long-term rate when central banks are running a more restrictive monetary policy, and at others, it will be below the long-term rate when policy needs to be eased.

The charts below illustrate the traditional three main currency blocks over this century: the euro, sterling, and the US dollar. Superimposed on each chart is a yellow line representing actual short-term rates. The charts also depict a range indicating a proxy for maximum easing and tightening, 200bps below and above the average, respectfully, which, for the purpose of this analysis, is considered an appropriate range based on our historic market observations.


Source: Bloomberg, as at December 2024


Source: Bloomberg, as at December 2024


Source: Bloomberg, as at December 2024

As policy has moved from tight to easy historically, short-term rates have reduced by 4% in these developed markets. There were times when this amount was lower, although this was due to the zero bound issue we discussed before. The new monetary policy easing tool of quantitative easing (QE) has had to be used in this century.

The market-implied analysis above demonstrates that yes, euro cash rates could well return to zero during the course of a normal economic cycle. However in the US and the UK, the lower band bottoms out at around 2%.

As an aside, the above charts also illustrate the extent of tightening the economy has faced over the last few years, with the yellow short-term rate lines all within ‘restrictive’ territory. As we have commented on before, and as economic textbooks have stated, monetary policy works with a lag, so it would be very unusual if 2025 is one of strong growth or inflation given the restrictive monetary policies pursued over the last 2 years.

The US, and consequently the global bond markets, were rightly focused on the November US election. With the election concluded, it is time to shift our attention from the 50 states to the state of the US economy, particularly the labour market, which is a key economic indicator for policy decisions.

Unlike in the past, not all jobs statistics are moving in the same direction and as a result, we are receiving mixed signal from the labour market. Take for example the JOLTS (Job Openings and Labour Turnover Survey) report, which is a monthly publication by the US Bureau of Labor Statistics that provides detailed insights into the US labour market. Depending on which indicators you decide to focus on, you can create a bull case or a bear case for the current state of the labour market.

Below is a slide representing the key indicators published in the JOLTS report. The charts on the left support the bull case for a robust economy. Job offers remain historically high, and layoffs are low, indicating a strong labour market. Conversely, the charts on the right illustrate the bear case. Both the quits rate and the hirings rate are low and at levels consistent with a recession.


Source: M&G, Bloomberg, 30 September 2024 (latest available data)

The market’s interpretation of economic data swings between these two perspectives. Strong economic data supports the bullish view, while weak data supports the bearish view. This dichotomy contributes to the volatility in interest rates as the economic outlook remains uncertain. The key question is whether the labour market is strong, weak, or perfectly balanced.

When considering all four charts together, one could argue that we have a neutral outlook for the labour market and, by extension, the overall economy. However, the divergence between the bullish and bearish indicators warrants further examination.

The chart below plots the quits rate against layoffs and discharges. The quits rate is driven by workers and reflects their confidence in the job market. When more employees voluntarily leave their jobs, it indicates that they are confident in their ability to find new, likely better, employment opportunities. This confidence usually stems from a robust job market with ample opportunities. Conversely, layoffs and discharges are decisions made by companies and generally reflect the underlying health of a company. The chart below shows an unusual divergence between these two lines. Workers seem hesitant to leave their jobs, suggesting weak labour market dynamics, while companies are behaving differently.

This relationship has significantly changed since the beginning of this decade, likely due to the unprecedented economic impact of the COVID-19 lockdowns. The T shaped recession has understandably affected how management approaches hiring and firing. Companies laid off employees quickly in 2020 and then struggled to rehire. This experience has changed their behaviour, leading to a tendency to hoard labour. This behavioural shift likely explains the current labour market puzzle: companies are not firing employees and are continuously looking for new hires. Consequently, redundancies are low, and theoretical job offers are plentiful. This labour hoarding behaviour could  account for the divergence between corporate and worker behaviour.


Source: M&G, Bloomberg, 30 September 2024 (latest available data)

The logical conclusion from the above chart is that while companies’ behaviour has changed, workers’ behaviour remains unaltered. The critical question is: how long companies will continue to hoard labour? The longer this behaviour persists, the stronger the economy will be.

If companies revert to a more traditional approach, moving away from labour hoarding, we would see a convergence in the data. Firings would increase, and job offers would decline. However, if companies decide to maintain their current approach, the economic outlook would involve less risk.

President-elect Trump is well known for his “You’re Fired” catchphrase. His appointments in his new administration suggest a downsizing of employment in the public sector. If this drive for efficiency is mirrored in the private sector, labour hoarding is likely to decrease rather than increase.

In conclusion, the US labour market presents a complex puzzle with indicators pointing in different directions. Understanding the underlying behavioural changes in corporate hiring and firing practices is crucial to interpreting these mixed signals and predicting future economic trends. If the corporate mood mimics the recent change in political culture then “You’re Fired” becomes a more likely corporate mantra.

Central banks have traditionally relied on interest rates as a primary tool to influence economic activity, raising rates to cool down an overheating economy, and cutting rates to stimulate growth. Historically, these mechanisms have worked fairly well; however, the recent cycle has proven to be different. Despite a series of aggressive rate hikes, the expected economic slowdown has been surprisingly muted, suggesting that economies are now less sensitive to interest rates. This raises a crucial question: if recent rate hikes haven’t significantly slowed the economy, how can we assume that traditional rate cuts will effectively stimulate it? And just how low must rates go to have an impact?

The housing market serves as a key channel for monetary policy transmission, making it essential to examine how it has responded to recent rate changes. Historically, the transmission mechanism from monetary policy to the housing market, and subsequently to the broader economy, was straightforward (as discussed here). However, this mechanism has become less predictable, especially post-financial crisis (discussed here). This monetary mechanism is not working as normal due to the unique nature of the current housing market.

The strength of the housing market depends on the balance between supply and demand. The housing inventory chart below illustrates the current bifurcation in this market, showing a sharp divergence between the average time new and existing homes stay on the market, with the availability of existing home inventories remaining low due to homeowners’ reluctance to sell, while new home inventories have risen as affordability challenges deter potential buyers:


Source: M&G, Bloomberg, 30 June 2024

On one side, existing homeowners, who have locked in historically low mortgage rates, have little incentive to move, since doing so would mean giving up those competitive rates. On the other side, new homebuyers are willing to buy but cannot afford to, as elevated mortgage rates have made housing largely unaffordable for them.

We therefore need to understand what level of rates is required to restore balance in the housing market and stimulate activity again. Starting with first-time buyers, the chart below shows their level of affordability, which, not surprisingly, is historically low. In order to restore affordability in this market, the line would have to return to 100, meaning that a median family would have just enough income to qualify for a mortgage loan on a median-priced home. To achieve this, we calculate that mortgage rates would need to drop to 3.4% (assuming all other factors remain constant).


Source: M&G, Bloomberg, August 2024

The situation with existing homeowners is different. For them, affordability is generally not an issue, given their lower loan-to-value ratios (LTVs). Instead, it is a matter of incentive. Aside from some exceptions, most people are not willing to move and thereby give up their extremely competitive mortgage rates. To incentivise most existing homeowners to move, rates would need to fall to levels similar to those they originally locked in. This would be around 3.5%, which is the average mortgage rate available during the period around COVID-19, when many either bought a house or refinanced their existing debt.


Source: M&G, Bloomberg, as at 30 June 2024

In conclusion, the transmission mechanism of interest rates has been dampened in the restrictive phase and will likely remain less effective in an easing phase. To effectively stimulate the U.S. economy through its housing channel, mortgage rates might need to fall significantly. Our analysis indicates that to restore activity in the housing market, mortgage rates might need to drop to around 3.5%. Historically, this would correspond to a reduction in the 10-year U.S. Treasury yield, potentially towards 2%, depending on broader economic conditions and Federal Reserve policy.


Source: M&G, Bloomberg, August 2024

We have written many times on QE (Quantitative Easing) and QT (Quantitative Tightening); however, we have never talked about QN. QN is the ultimate goal for central banks – but what exactly is it?

The ‘N’ in QN stands for Neutral. In a steady state of economic growth, money must be printed to facilitate inflation in the economy. In this steady state, there is a simple requirement to have enough money tokens in the system to achieve the desired growth in the nominal GDP of the country, which is defined as the combination of real growth and inflation.

We can plot this monetary policy stance over time by showing money supply growth vs nominal GDP. In the chart below we can see that the US Central Bank normally pursues a 6 percent annual growth in money supply to achieve 4 percent growth in nominal GDP, composed on average of 2 percent of real growth and 2 percent of inflation.


Source: Bloomberg, 31 March 2024

Given the series of economic events over the course of the first quarter of this century, unconventional monetary policy has been regularly occurring. QE has been in operation on and off over much of the period, in order to facilitate stable growth in the money supply. As mentioned earlier, in the 20 years prior to Covid, the Fed generally succeeded in maintaining a stable level of money supply growth. However, the aggressive QE measures implemented since Covid have led to a significant increase in the money supply, contributing to the subsequent inflationary pressures.

Since June 2022, the Fed has reversed its course and initiated a round of QT to gradually reduce the amount of money in circulation.

The question now is, how much more do they need to do? If we assume the amount of money in the system should approximate to the size of the economy, we need to plot the size of the economy versus the size of money supply to attempt to solve the balance sheet conundrum, which we have done.


Source: Bloomberg, 31 March 2024

In the chart above, we shade the area representing excess money. This excess money will be inflationary in nature, as discussed before here. We can see that QT is getting very close to the point where this excess inflationary money stock is going to disappear. Theoretically, this looks like December of this year. At this point in the stylised picture we provide, monetary policy should be run in a QN framework to allow natural economic growth and inflation of around 2 percent to be facilitated[1].

This move to a more normal monetary approach is something that central banks need to approach over the near term as they transition from a ‘cancel culture’ to ‘business as usual’. 

Monetary policy is acknowledged to work with long and variable lags. If we get to December and real QT persists, or the central banks are not expanding the cash in the system at the QN rate, then there would, by definition, be a monetarist argument for inflation to be below their target. If this were to transpire, then inflation would potentially be low enough to encourage significant interest rate cuts.

NET monetary policy matters. Going forward, it will be crucial to understand what central banks will decide to do: will they move to a more Neutral stance? Will they change course completely and adopt a policy of Easing? Or will they opt for continuous Tightening?

[1] To note, the above assumptions are based on the current pace of QT. Whilst the Federal Reserve plans to taper its Quantitative Tightening program, should the pace of QT be reduced, it is likely that the point where the two lines cross could be pushed further back. Further, M2 is influenced by both the Fed and commercial banks through their lending activities; however, for simplicity, the above assumptions are solely dictated by the Fed’s QT, so could be impacted by other factors. Despite this, given high interest rates and lower lending activity, it is likely that the Fed’s QT will be the dominant factor impacting M2 levels in the short term.

We have spent over 15 years talking about quantitative easing (QE) and quantitative tightening (QT). Each phase of QE has become increasingly more significant, resulting in a huge final dose of monetary creation in response to the COVID crisis. This money is now being cancelled.

To recap QE is the printing of money. Theoretically, this is expected to be inflationary. Increasing the supply of something will reduce its value, all else being equal. Traditionally this was implemented with old world technology: the printing press and then reversed in the furnace. It is now achieved electronically: money created from thin air at the magic press of a computer button, and cancelled in the same manner.

The original fears when this innovative measure was introduced were that the increase in the supply of money  would have the understandable side effect of increasing inflation. This did not occur in the first phases of QE. Therefore, the policy became more acceptable. The link between the money supply and inflation appeared to be theoretical only, given the real world results. However, the empirical evidence of late would point to the opposite conclusion. Too much QE does result in inflation. I discussed this further in my previous September 2022 blog. The central banks are now tackling this inflation and they have been taking aggressive action to solve the problem. They have two prongs of attack: conventional rate hikes – which have been historically strong over the last year – and QT. 

The charts below show the broad relationship between money supply growth and inflation. There is a historical observable link between the creation of money and inflation. This monetary lag of around 18 months is a constant feature of the economy and markets.


Source: Bloomberg, BLS, Federal Reserve, 31 March 2023

From the charts it is pretty clear that the recent inflationary surge is potentially a function of money supply growth. Strangely, this is something central bankers do not focus on. Maybe because of the data set they have from early QE? From a monetarist point of view this is a mistake, as espoused elegantly by Tim Congdon. I have a great deal of sympathy for his views. It seems strange that Central Bankers recognise that supply demand dynamics are important: a shortage of energy, labour and microchips are all inflationary, but they don’t seem to recognise that an abundance of printed money reduces its price  – A.K.A. inflation!

The most interesting point on this chart is the degree of monetary cancellation: it is historically unprecedented. On a simple reading, this is hugely deflationary and  suggests that inflation will reach new lows. The culture of cancelling money has not yet reached its zenith. We know that central banks are signalling that this process will continue and we can assume that money supply growth is likely to remain negative for some time. This is a new grand experiment.

Which is correct? Is money supply growth inflationary or not? One way of squaring the circle of early vs late QE would be to analyse where the printed money went. During early QE, it simply filled the bank vaults to make banks solvent against depositor runs, and paid for previous lending mistakes, refilling the reservoir due to the drying up of financial markets. The later stages of QE resulted in cash overflowing from banks into the real economy, and therefore brought about inflationary consequences. Is it the environment that QE is undertaken in that determines the inflationary outcome?

One way to maybe perceive this is to analyse the recent woes in regional US banks. Cancelling money through QT results in less money in the economy. Therefore, banks will have less deposits on aggregate. If this deposit drain is focused evenly across the system then the effects on each institution are minimal, but if that drain of potential reserves all comes out of one institution, then that bank will face problems. Printing money to provide liquidity and reserves to support the weak banks in the first stage of QE has been replaced with cancelling reserves via QT, challenging the weaker banks.

Most investors didn’t seem to be too worried about inflation 18 months ago when money supply reached a historical high. Now inflation is at the forefront of our minds, but money supply is negative. This cancel culture of quantitative tightening is a new monetary phenomenon. Should we be starting to think more about deflation than inflation next year?

‘inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon, in the sense that it is and can be produced only by a more rapid increase in the quantity of money than the output’ – Milton Friedman


Source: Federal Reserve, 26 April 2023

Quantitative tightening (QT) is due to start in earnest on the 1st November – just in time for Halloween! The Bank of England is scheduled to start a serious active sale programme of the assets it bought during QE, which was a ‘treat’ for the holders of the assets and was a policy measure they had to undertake to stimulate the economy as rates were at the lower bound. It is now time for the ‘trick’. The Bank describes on its own website why it engages in QE… let’s see how they would describe QT:

Edited extract from bankofengland.co.uk, “How does quantitative easing work?”

Source: https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetary-policy/quantitative-easing, M&G

QE was stimulative, QT is designed to restrict growth. We believe QE increased inflation – therefore, via reducing the outstanding stock of money, QT will act as an inflation dampener.

One of the potential side effects not mentioned in the Bank of England guide is the potential effect on Sterling. The transmission mechanism of interest rate changes affecting currencies is a potential catalyst for FX moves.

Another direct effect of QE/QT is that the excess supply of something reduces its value and vice versa. We would therefore expect currencies where the central bank pursues QE to have weaker currencies and currencies where the central bank implements QT to have stronger currencies. When all countries are printing or destroying money in unison then the effect is not noticeable. However, when one country is printing and the other is destroying its money, then the latter currency should be stronger. This explains the scary chart below.


Source: M&G, Bloomberg (24 October 2022).

QT will slow the economy and fight inflation for the reasons explained above. This policy aim could be further helped by subsequent strengthening of the currency.

Following on from the recession blog we said we would discuss inflation: this is the big difference in the economic cycle this time around as illustrated in the chart below.

Source: M&G, Bloomberg (31 August 2022)

The common cause of the current inflation according to many commentators is the supply shortage, whether that be commodities, manufacturing or labour. Central bankers frequently have pointed to these effects: “Supply-side constraints have gotten worse,” said Fed Chair Powell at the end of last year. “The risks are clearly now to longer and more-persistent bottlenecks, and thus to higher inflation.”[1]

These issues contribute to the inflationary outcome: supply and demand matter. Inflation however is the balance of relative supply of money versus what that money buys. This is an area that central banks are not commenting on as much. We will explore this issue today.

Below shows a chart of the increase in supply of money per unit of output as measured by M2/GDP. Against this we plot inflation outcomes in the same economies. As the economic textbook would say, increasing the supply of money is a major influence on inflation. To put it simply, the supply drought in goods and services has been met by a deluge of supply of money. It can be argued that it is the excessive abundance of money that is contributing significantly to current inflation. 

Source: M&G, Bloomberg (30 June 2022)

We have discussed previously the way helicopter money works. Central banks are now trying to return money supply growth to more normal levels and trying to collapse the outstanding monetary surplus by quantitative tightening. The central banks have 3 policy options to implement if they decide to clean up this flood of cash.

Firstly, they could simply let it dry in the sun. This would involve accepting the inflation they caused, and hope for no secondary inflationary effects embedding into the economy, primarily through changes in inflation expectations. This dovish policy would mean not altering the money stock and letting the impetus of previous policy simply die out.

Secondly, they could mop up the liquidity by doing some quantitative tightening so bringing future inflation under control at a faster pace.

Thirdly, they could implement a cyclone policy of rapid tightened by sucking back up as much money out of the economy as they dare. A rapid collapse in inflation would ensue but this cyclone approach would risk damaging the wider economy.

Central banks are likely to follow a pattern somewhere between the first and second option. This means inflation will persist but will then fall with the usual monetary lag, as indeed it surged with the usual monetary lag. Inflation will therefore likely be temporary but the definition of the period of ‘temporary’ is in central bankers’ own hands.

The current inflation conversation is based around supply constraints of goods and services. Maybe the debate should be more about supply constraints of money being implemented to bring inflation down. Central banks can get inflation back to target – it is a question of how quickly they decide to do it.

 [1] https://www.wsj.com/articles/fed-chairman-jerome-powell-says-supply-side-constraints-are-creating-more-inflation-risk-11634917630

The economic backdrop post Covid remains one of great uncertainty regarding recession risks for credit, and inflation risks for bonds. We will attempt to address these issues in two blogs. The first will focus on our usual starting point over the years regarding the risk of recession; the second will explore the current inflation outlook from a fresh perspective, as we have not faced such high inflation in developed economies for many years.

Over the years we have looked at 3 key indicators of recession risk. The most recent occasions were at the start of the Covid pandemic and again earlier this year. Today we will update this as these indicators of recession risk have moved.

The first of these is the rightly well-favoured primary indication of upcoming recession: the inverted yield curve indicator. This has a good track record and is pointing to a sure recession ahead – it is the most inverted it has been in years as illustrated below, and one would argue is glowing red.

Source: M&G, Bloomberg (31 August 2022)

The second warning light comes from the price of oil. Below we can once again see its predictive powers. Currently the oil price indicator at a formulaic level looks amber, given recent weakness. I would argue that is not a recession warning for the USA, though other significant economies face a more recession risk due to currency weakness – in the case of Europe, the region also faces an historic energy price shock due to its reliance on Russian gas. Given the above I would also argue that energy is a potential red light for some economies.

Source: M&G, Bloomberg (31 August 2022)

Historically we have always looked for a third confirming signal of upcoming recession. The basic premise of this is that the Fed-induced inverted yield curve is created to fight inflation, usually from an energy shock, and this policy must find its way into the real economy. This transmission mechanism has historically happened through the housing market. We plot the likely direction of the housing market by looking at its sales-to-inventory ratio: when it takes a few months to sell available housing stock, the economy is set fair; when it takes longer than around 7 months, the economy faces problems ahead. This is illustrated below.

Source: M&G, Bloomberg (31 July 2022)

You can see from the historical graph above that this is a good indicator. We are faced with a dilemma when we update the data to today however, as we currently have a significant divergence between existing homes for sale inventory and new home for sales inventory. The former shows a robust healthy economy, while the latter implies an economy on the brink of an all-mighty recession. Let’s try to understand the difference.

I think the reason for this divergence is the dramatic move in interest rates, from record lows to more typical rates, shown below. Different households face dramatically different interest rates. New buyers face the full force of Fed tightening, while existing holders will not sell as they will lose their locked in low rates if they move. This results in less demand for new build, slowing demand, and less supply of existing homes, slowing supply and explaining the dramatic divergence. Which is more important for the economy: the GDP impetus from new build housing, or the fact the majority of housing supply is now off market and so supporting prices and therefore consumer confidence? This ambiguity means this indicator could be bright green or bright red.

Source: M&G, Bloomberg (16 September 2022)

There is one other factor that is potentially very different this time and this is our often discussed labour market data. In a recession, unemployment by definition increases as shown below. This time around, we start in a very strange position with excess demand for labour at record levels. We would therefore need to work through this excess demand before we started increasing unemployment and experiencing a recession. This points to a delay or potential postponement of recession compared to a normal economic cycle.

Source: M&G, Bloomberg (31 July 2022)

Traditional measures such as the yield curve point to a recession round the corner, with supporting indicators pushing generally in the same direction. The cushion of labour demand points to a potentially different outcome at least in the short term. Recession is highly probable to be further away than that implied by the most important signal, the inverted yield curve.

One other thing that is different this time is the historic inflation we have that is influencing central bank policy.  We will focus on this in a second blog later today.

“The fundamental change in our framework is that we’re not going to act pre-emptively based on forecasts for the most part and we’re going to wait to see actual data. I think it will take people time to adjust to that and to adjust to that new practice, and the only way we can really build the credibility of that is by doing it.” 

Fed Chair Powell, 17 March 2021 via Bloomberg (19 March)

The market’s very own Top Gun made the Maverick statement above, emphasising the significant change in the monetary policy reaction function that took place just last year. This was a huge signal that they were prepared to run the economy hot, and boy did they break Mach 10! This theme was central to our Bravo Yankee Pappa blog. Central banks were going to escape the zero bound, we thought they would, but not by the stellar amount they actually have with inflation hitting generational highs.

Source: Bloomberg, 31 May 2022 (latest data available). 

This maverick manoeuvre in monetary policy is not what you expect to see from central banks – though given the low inflation altitude going into the Covid shock they needed to ditch the usual playbook. The markets are rightly very concerned now over the immediate outlook as they face a set of dangerous parameters that are new to them. What will the central bankers do next? Powell has two options:

  1. Powell could stick to his words above and stay reactionary, not proactive. Following this flight path implies super aggressive tightening to kill inflation, with recession of various degrees being accepted as collateral damage. This would imply high real yields at least in the short term and be bad news for credit, and likely lead to a high degree of market volatility as the Fed reacts in real time to real time data.
  2. Powell could recognise that he executed a one-off manoeuvre in monetary policy in exceptional circumstances and that we should find a flight path back to the conventional monetary policy of the past.

I think option 1 is not where Powell’s thoughts lie.

A maverick is someone who is prepared to think differently and unconventionally: I don’t think that is the right call sign for Powell or any central banker! In fact most central bankers would aspire to the Iceman call sign: intelligent, analytical, calm, though with the right amount of swagger to get under the market’s skin. How do they get from the current stated policy to the old playbook?

Central bankers could simply recognise the one-off battle predicament they found themselves in during 2020, and announce a return to their more pre-emptive Iceman approach. They can therefore temporarily ignore the ground-breaking inflation as a rule that had to be broken for a greater good. This would mean a period of above average inflation, and no need for a significant economic downturn.

The central banks will have difficulty in transitioning to the old approach: they will push rates higher, they will reverse QE, and maybe fly higher above the zero inflation bound on a permanent basis. Hopefully they do this in the style of Iceman, patient and forward looking as opposed to reactive, and therefore we can escape the current danger zone.

Author: Richard Woolnough

Get Bond Vigilantes updates straight to your inbox

Sign up to the BV Mailing List